Buy new:
$27.16
FREE delivery Tuesday, May 21 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Ships from: Amazon
Sold by: Shakespeare Book House
$27.16
Get Fast, Free Shipping with Amazon Prime FREE Returns
FREE delivery Tuesday, May 21 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Or fastest delivery Wednesday, May 15. Order within 1 hr 5 mins
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
$$27.16 () Includes selected options. Includes initial monthly payment and selected options. Details
Price
Subtotal
$$27.16
Subtotal
Initial payment breakdown
Shipping cost, delivery date, and order total (including tax) shown at checkout.
Ships from
Amazon
Ships from
Amazon
Returns
30-day easy returns
30-day easy returns
This item can be returned in its original condition for a full refund or replacement within 30 days of receipt.
Returns
30-day easy returns
This item can be returned in its original condition for a full refund or replacement within 30 days of receipt.
Payment
Secure transaction
Your transaction is secure
We work hard to protect your security and privacy. Our payment security system encrypts your information during transmission. We don’t share your credit card details with third-party sellers, and we don’t sell your information to others. Learn more
Payment
Secure transaction
We work hard to protect your security and privacy. Our payment security system encrypts your information during transmission. We don’t share your credit card details with third-party sellers, and we don’t sell your information to others. Learn more
$11.71
Get Fast, Free Shipping with Amazon Prime FREE Returns
Contains limited highlighting and/or writing. Minimal signs of wear. 100% satisfaction guaranteed. Contains limited highlighting and/or writing. Minimal signs of wear. 100% satisfaction guaranteed. See less
FREE delivery Tuesday, May 21 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Or fastest delivery Wednesday, May 15. Order within 5 mins
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
$$27.16 () Includes selected options. Includes initial monthly payment and selected options. Details
Price
Subtotal
$$27.16
Subtotal
Initial payment breakdown
Shipping cost, delivery date, and order total (including tax) shown at checkout.
Access codes and supplements are not guaranteed with used items.
Kindle app logo image

Download the free Kindle app and start reading Kindle books instantly on your smartphone, tablet, or computer - no Kindle device required.

Read instantly on your browser with Kindle for Web.

Using your mobile phone camera - scan the code below and download the Kindle app.

QR code to download the Kindle App

Something went wrong. Please try your request again later.

The Hollow Hope: Can Courts Bring About Social Change? Second Edition (American Politics and Political Economy Series) Paperback – May 1, 2008

4.5 4.5 out of 5 stars 65 ratings

There is a newer edition of this item:

{"desktop_buybox_group_1":[{"displayPrice":"$27.16","priceAmount":27.16,"currencySymbol":"$","integerValue":"27","decimalSeparator":".","fractionalValue":"16","symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"HpNQk8Simm0HVO69UMef6uyhbFRuwEG73%2BG%2Foqgzypymp3RuOl%2Fm8MB0Nq75jvK6GZ8FuDVE3RzhNp6sEZSL0%2BZZ0rCl0265M9jcX1Tgh%2F7AOEXAI%2BLbhO8s7jRqJ8e%2FN3TkUopAsPOLPKeJkX%2BhrxC25o96yzIQ09Fy4odRWSUcfZ82yD6oedHZ%2BxbDMGRz","locale":"en-US","buyingOptionType":"NEW","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":0}, {"displayPrice":"$11.71","priceAmount":11.71,"currencySymbol":"$","integerValue":"11","decimalSeparator":".","fractionalValue":"71","symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"HpNQk8Simm0HVO69UMef6uyhbFRuwEG7EpmjMM5YYXR61Um48az4LEqS%2BMcMleJdrOowhH4XrOryX4Jl3srXlgUWvvy544rpJibDYjGSglMFcdHGh1gmOggAip19xCscPXPL%2FZXpEIQUkDZQyPlWVhV2TZED7fBjlP3zvGaDtO4WXINFPtgB2nOwrMrepH%2BN","locale":"en-US","buyingOptionType":"USED","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":1}]}

Purchase options and add-ons


In follow-up studies, dozens of reviews, and even a book of essays evaluating his conclusions, Gerald Rosenberg’s critics—not to mention his supporters—have spent nearly two decades debating the arguments he first put forward in
The Hollow Hope. With this substantially expanded second edition of his landmark work, Rosenberg himself steps back into the fray, responding to criticism and adding chapters on the same-sex marriage battle that ask anew whether courts can spur political and social reform.
            Finding that the answer is still a resounding no, Rosenberg reaffirms his powerful contention that it’s nearly impossible to generate significant reforms through litigation. The reason? American courts are ineffective and relatively weak—far from the uniquely powerful sources for change they’re often portrayed as. Rosenberg supports this claim by documenting the direct and secondary effects of key court decisions—particularly
Brown v. Board of Education and Roe v. Wade. He reveals, for example, that Congress, the White House, and a determined civil rights movement did far more than Brown to advance desegregation, while pro-choice activists invested too much in Roe at the expense of political mobilization. Further illuminating these cases, as well as the ongoing fight for same-sex marriage rights, Rosenberg also marshals impressive evidence to overturn the common assumption that even unsuccessful litigation can advance a cause by raising its profile.
            Directly addressing its critics in a new conclusion,
The Hollow Hope, Second Edition promises to reignite for a new generation the national debate it sparked seventeen years ago.
Read more Read less

The Amazon Book Review
The Amazon Book Review
Book recommendations, author interviews, editors' picks, and more. Read it now

Frequently bought together

$27.16
Get it as soon as Tuesday, May 21
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
Sold by Shakespeare Book House and ships from Amazon Fulfillment.
+
$62.99
Get it as soon as Monday, May 20
In Stock
Ships from and sold by Amazon.com.
+
$15.99
Get it as soon as Sunday, May 19
Only 15 left in stock (more on the way).
Ships from and sold by Amazon.com.
Total price:
To see our price, add these items to your cart.
Details
Added to Cart
Some of these items ship sooner than the others.
Choose items to buy together.

Editorial Reviews

About the Author


Gerald N. Rosenberg is associate professor of political science emeritus and a lecturer of law at the University of Chicago. He is a member of the Washington, DC, bar.

Excerpt. © Reprinted by permission. All rights reserved.

The Hollow Hope

Can Courts Bring About Social Change?

By Gerald N. Rosenberg

The University of Chicago Press

Copyright © 2008 The University of Chicago
All rights reserved.
ISBN: 978-0-226-72671-7

Contents

List of Tables and Figures,
Preface to the Second Edition,
Preface to the First Edition,
Introduction,
1. The Dynamic and the Constrained Court,
Part 1 • Civil Rights,
Introduction,
2. Bound for Glory? Brown and the Civil Rights Revolution,
3. Constraints, Conditions, and the Courts,
4. Planting the Seeds of Progress?,
5. The Current of History,
Part 2 • Abortion and Women's Rights,
Introduction,
6. Transforming Women's Lives? The Courts and Abortion,
7. Liberating Women? The Courts and Women's Rights,
8. The Court as Catalyst?,
9. The Tide of History,
Part 3 • The Environment, Reapportionment, and Criminal Law,
Introduction,
10. Cleaning House? The Courts, the Environment, and Reapportionment,
11. Judicial Revolution? Litigation to Reform the Criminal Law,
Part 4 • Same-Sex Marriage,
Introduction,
12. You've Got That Loving Feeling? The Litigation Campaign for Same-Sex Marriage,
13. Confusing Rights with Reality: Litigation for Same-Sex Marriage and the Counter-Mobilization of Law,
14. Conclusion: The Fly-Paper Court,
Epilogue,
Appendices,
1. Black Children in Elementary and Secondary School with Whites: 1954–72,
2. Blacks at Predominantly White Public Colleges and Universities,
3. Black Voter Registration in the Southern States: Pre- and Post-Voting Rights Act,
4. Laws and Actions Designed to Preserve Segregation,
5. Method for Obtaining Information for Table 4.1 and Figure 4.1,
6. Illegal Abortions,
7. Method for Obtaining Information for Tables 8.1A, 8.1B, 8.2A, and 8.2B, and for Figures 8.1 and 8.2,
8. Coding Rules and Methods for Obtaining Information for Tables 13.3, 13.4, 13.5, 13.6, and 13.7,
Case References,
Notes,
References,
Index,


CHAPTER 1

The Dynamic and the Constrained Court


What is the role of U.S. courts in producing significant social reform? When and under what conditions will U.S. courts be effective producers of significant social reform? When does it make sense for individuals and groups pressing for such change to litigate? What kinds of effects from court victories can they expect? Which view best captures the reality of American politics? Given the alleged success of the social reform litigation of the last four decades, and Americans' attachment to the Dynamic Court view, it is tempting to suggest that it always makes sense for groups to litigate. On the other hand, our attachment to the vision of the Constrained Court, as well as a knowledge of legal history, can suggest that courts can never be effective producers of significant social reform. But "always" and "never" are claims about frequency, not conditions. To fully understand the role of the courts in producing significant social reform, we must focus on the latter.

Many scholars have turned their attention to the questions this litigation activity raises. However, their findings remain unconnected and not squarely centered on whether, and under what conditions, courts produce significant social reform. Some writing has focused on the determinants of winning court cases rather than on the effects of court decisions. Galanter (1974), for example, asks "why the 'haves' come out ahead" and suggests that the resources and experience available to established and on-going groups provide an advantage in litigation. Similarly, Handler (1978), while exploring outcomes as well as the resources available to litigants, stresses the latter too. While these and similar works provide interesting theories about winning cases, that is a different question from the effects courts have on political and social change.

On the outcome side, there are numerous individual studies. Unfortunately, they tend to focus narrowly on a given issue and refrain from offering hypotheses about courts and change. More self-consciously theoretical case studies have examined admittedly non-controversial areas (Rebell and Block 1982), the need for federal pressure to improve race relations (Hochschild 1984), or have suggested so many hypotheses (one hundred and thirty-five of them) as to be of little practical help (Wasby 1970, 246-66). Finally, the extensive law review literature on institutional reform either lacks evidence or focuses on individual cases with little or no attempt to generate hypotheses. While much of this work is well done, it does not address the larger question.

In the bulk of this chapter, I flesh out the two views. My aim is to make each view plausible, if not enticing. Then, critically examining evidence for their plausibility, I develop a set of constraints and conditions under which courts can produce significant social reform. These suggest that both views oversimplify court effectiveness.


Structural Constraints: The Logic of the Constrained Court View

The view of courts as unable to produce significant social reform has a distinguished pedigree reaching back to the founders. Premised on the institutional structure of the American political system and the procedures and belief systems created by American law, it suggests that the conditions required for courts to produce significant social reform will seldom exist. Unpacked, the Constrained Court view maintains that courts will generally not be effective producers of significant social reform for three reasons: the limited nature of constitutional rights, the lack of judicial independence, and the judiciary's inability to develop appropriate policies and its lack of powers of implementation.


The Limited Nature of Rights

The Constitution, and the set of beliefs that surround it, is not unbounded. Certain rights are enshrined in it and others are rejected. In economic terms, private control over the allocation and distribution of resources, the use of property, is protected (Miller 1968). "Rights" to certain minimums, or equal shares of basic goods, are not. Further, judicial discretion is bound by the norms and expectations of the legal culture. These two parameters, believers in the Constrained Court view suggest, present a problem for litigators pressing the courts for significant social reform because most such litigation is based on constitutional claims that rights are being denied. An individual or group comes into a court claiming it is being denied some benefit, or protection from arbitrary and discriminatory action, and that it is entitled to this benefit or that protection. Proponents of the Constrained Court view suggest that this has four important consequences for social reformers.

First, they argue, it limits the sorts of claims that can be made, for not all social reform goals can be plausibly presented in the name of constitutional rights. For example, there are no constitutional rights to decent housing, adequate levels of welfare, or clean air, while there are constitutional rights to minimal governmental interference in the use of one's property. This may mean that "practically significant but legally irrelevant policy matters may remain beyond the purview of the court" (Note 1977, 436). Further, as Gordon (1984, 111) suggests, "the legal forms we use set limits on what we can imagine as practical outcomes." Thus, the nature of rights in the U.S. legal system, embedded in the Constitution, may constrain the courts in producing significant social reform by preventing them from hearing many claims.

A second consequence from the Constrained Court perspective is that, even where claims can be made, social reformers must often argue for the establishment of a new right, or the extension of a generally accepted right to a new situation. In welfare rights litigation, for example, the Court was asked to find a constitutional right to welfare (Krislov 1973). This need to push the courts to read the Constitution in an expansive or "liberal" way creates two main difficulties. Underlying these difficulties is judicial awareness of the need for predictability in the law and the politically exposed nature of judges whose decisions go beyond the positions of electorally accountable officials. First, the Constitution, lawyers, judges, and legal academics form a dominant legal culture that at any given time accepts some rights and not others and sets limits on the interpretation and expansion of rights. Judicial discretion is bound by the beliefs and norms of this legal culture, and decisions that stray too far from them are likely to be reversed and severely criticized. Put simply, courts, and the judges that compose them, even if sympathetic to social reform plaintiffs, may be unwilling to risk crossing this nebulous yet real boundary. Second, and perhaps more important, is the role of precedent and what Justice Traynor calls the "continuity scripts of the law" (Traynor 1977, 11). Traynor, a justice of the California Supreme Court for twenty-five years, Chief Justice from 1964 to 1970, and known as a judge open to new ideas, wrote of the "very caution of the judicial process" (1977, 7). Arguing that "a judge must plod rather than soar," Traynor saw that the "greatest judges" proceed "at the pace of a tortoise that steadily makes advances though it carries the past on its back" (1977, 7, 6). Constrained by precedent and the beliefs of the dominant legal culture, judges, the Constrained Court view asserts, are not likely to act as crusaders.

Third, supporters of the Constrained Court view note, as Scheingold (1974) points out, that to claim a right in court is to accept the procedures and obligations of the legal system. These procedures are designed, in part, to make it difficult for courts to hear certain kinds of cases. As the Council for Public Interest Law (CPIL) puts it, doctrines of standing and of class actions, the so-called political question doctrine, the need to have a live controversy, and other technical doctrines can "deter courts from deciding cases on the merits" (CPIL 1976, 355) and can result in social reform groups being unable to present their best arguments, or even have their day in court. Once in court, however, the legal process tends to dissipate significant social reform by making appropriate remedies unlikely. This can occur, McCann (1986, 200) points out, because policy-based litigation aimed at significant social reform is usually "disaggregate[d] ... into discrete conflicts among limited actors over specific individual entitlements." Remedial decrees, it has been noted, "must not confuse what is socially or judicially desirable with what is legally required" (Special Project 1978, 855). Thus, litigation seldom deals with "underlying issues and problems" and is "directed more toward symptoms than causes" (Harris and Spiller 1976, 26).

Finally, it has long been argued that framing issues in legally sound ways robs them of "political and purposive appeal" (Handler 1978, 33). In the narrow sense, the technical nature of legal argument can denude issues of emotional, widespread appeal. More broadly, there is the danger that litigation by the few will replace political action by the many and reduce the democratic nature of the American polity. James Bradley Thayer, writing in 1901, was concerned that reliance on litigation would sap the democratic process of its vitality. He warned that the "tendency of a common and easy resort" to the courts, especially in asking them to invalidate acts of the democratically accountable branches, would "dwarf the political capacity of the people" (Thayer 1901, 107). This view was echoed more recently by McCann, who found that litigation-prone activists' "legal rights approach to expanding democracy has significantly narrowed their conception of political action itself" (McCann 1986, 26). Expanding the point, McCann argued that "legal tactics not only absorb scarce resources that could be used for popular mobilization ... [but also] make it difficult to develop broadly based, multiissue grassroots associations of sustained citizen allegiance" (McCann 1986, 200). For these reasons, the Constrained Court view suggests that the nature of rights in the U.S. constrains courts from being effective producers of significant social reform. Thus,

Constraint I: The bounded nature of constitutional rights prevents courts from hearing or effectively acting on many significant social reform claims, and lessens the chances of popular mobilization.


Limits on Judicial Independence — The Institutional Factor

As the colloquy between Justice Jackson and U. S. Attorney Rankin illustrates, reformers have often turned to courts when opposition to significant social reform in the other branches has prevented them from acting. Thus, much significant social reform litigation takes place in the context of stalemate within, or opposition from, the other branches. For courts to be effective in such situations, they must, logically, be independent of those other branches. Supporters of the Constrained Court view point to a broad array of evidence that suggests the founders did not thoroughly insulate courts or provide them with unfailing independence.

To start, the appointment process, of course, limits judicial independence. Judges do not select themselves. Rather, they are chosen by politicians, the president and the Senate at the federal level. Presidents, while not clairvoyant, tend to nominate judges who they think will represent their judicial philosophies. Clearly, changing court personnel can bring court decisions into line with prevailing political opinion (and dampen support for significant social reform). Thus, the Constrained Court perspective sees the appointment process as limiting judicial independence.

Judicial independence requires that court decisions, in comparison to legislation, do not invariably reflect public opinion. Supporters of the Constrained Court view note, however, that Supreme Court decisions, historically, have seldom strayed far from what was politically acceptable (McCloskey 1960, 223–24). Rather than suggesting independence, this judicial unwillingness to often blaze its own trail perhaps suggests, in the words of Finley Peter Dunne's Mr. Dooley, that "th' supreme coort follows th' iliction returns" (Dunne 1901, 26).

In at least two important ways, the Constrained Court view suggests, Congress may constrain court actions. First, in the statutory area, Congress can override decisions, telling the courts they misinterpreted the intent of the law. That is, Congress may rewrite a provision to meet court objections or simply state more clearly what it meant so that the courts' reading of the law is repudiated. Second, although Congress cannot directly reverse decisions based on constitutional interpretations, presumably untouchable by the democratic process, it may be able to constrain them by threatening certain changes in the legal structure. A large part of the reason, of course, is the appointment process. But even without the power of appointment, the Court may be susceptible to credible threats against it. Historical review of the relations of the Court to the other branches of the federal government suggests that the Court cannot for long stand alone against such pressure. From the "Court-packing" plan of FDR to recent bills proposing to remove federal court jurisdiction over certain issues, court-curbing proposals may allow Congress to constrain courts as producers of significant social reform (Nagel 1965; Rosenberg 1985; cf. Lasser 1988).

American courts, proponents of the Constrained Court view claim, are particularly deferential to the positions of the federal government. On the Supreme Court level, the solicitor general is accorded a special role. The office has unusual access to the Court and is often asked by the Court to intervene in cases and present the government's position. When the solicitor general petitions the Court to enter a case, the Court almost invariably grants the request, regardless of the position of the parties. The government is also unusually successful in convincing the Court to hear cases it appeals and to not hear those it opposes. The solicitor general's access to the Court carries over to the winning of cases. Historically, the solicitor general (or the side the government is supporting when it enters a case as amicus) wins about 70 percent of the time (Scigliano 1971; Ulmer and Willison 1985). It appears that the federal government has both extraordinary access to and persuasive abilities with the Court (Ducat and Dudley 1985; Dudley and Ducat 1986). That does not comport with notions of independence and a judicial system able to defy legislative and political majorities. Thus, the Constrained Court view's adherents believe,

Constraint II: The judiciary lacks the necessary independence from the other branches of the government to produce significant social reform.


(Continues...)Excerpted from The Hollow Hope by Gerald N. Rosenberg. Copyright © 2008 The University of Chicago. Excerpted by permission of The University of Chicago Press.
All rights reserved. No part of this excerpt may be reproduced or reprinted without permission in writing from the publisher.
Excerpts are provided by Dial-A-Book Inc. solely for the personal use of visitors to this web site.

Product details

  • Publisher ‏ : ‎ University of Chicago Press; Second edition (May 1, 2008)
  • Language ‏ : ‎ English
  • Paperback ‏ : ‎ 525 pages
  • ISBN-10 ‏ : ‎ 0226726711
  • ISBN-13 ‏ : ‎ 978-0226726717
  • Item Weight ‏ : ‎ 1.75 pounds
  • Dimensions ‏ : ‎ 8.81 x 6.06 x 1.18 inches
  • Customer Reviews:
    4.5 4.5 out of 5 stars 65 ratings

About the author

Follow authors to get new release updates, plus improved recommendations.
Gerald N. Rosenberg
Brief content visible, double tap to read full content.
Full content visible, double tap to read brief content.

Discover more of the author’s books, see similar authors, read author blogs and more

Customer reviews

4.5 out of 5 stars
4.5 out of 5
65 global ratings

Top reviews from the United States

Reviewed in the United States on May 13, 2014
you will have a misprint that starts on page 51. make sure that you get a new one. but otherwise the book is a very good source of information regarding the role of the courts in creating social change... or not. It is very debatable, this was the text that I used in a class so during the entirety of the book I was able to contradict or counter the arguments made.
One person found this helpful
Report
Reviewed in the United States on January 2, 2020
good condition of book
Reviewed in the United States on May 9, 2017
Was recommended to me by political commentator Ben Shapiro. Absolutely fantastic book and would recommend to anyone interested in the court's role during the Civil Rights movement!
Reviewed in the United States on April 26, 2011
Gerald Rosenberg in The Hollow Hope presents a thought provocative theory about the ability of courts to bring about social change. Rosenberg considers landmark cases such as Brown v. Board of Education, Roe v. Wade, and others and argues in amazingly convincing detail that the court action made little difference in the desegregation movement or the abortion debate and that in some cases a strategy of litigation has proven counter productive. This is a dramatic departure from the more traditional view of these cases that they are iconic symbols of social change. Courts because of their structures and lack of implementation power are actually poor agents of social change unless the executive and legislative branches are prepared to provide the federal teeth to say integrate schools a movement that occurred a full decade after the original Brown case was decided. Would've gone five stars but for two complaints, it felt to me that the cases like Brown and Roe where underestimated. There was still something valuable in the fact a governing body ruled that such rights exist, even if political leaders were unwilling to act. Secondly, the section on abortion could use an update to include Casey and any post 1991 cases. Overall, a provocative book that altered my thinking on social change litigation.
5 people found this helpful
Report
Reviewed in the United States on January 11, 2019
Get lot of information from this book ,
Reviewed in the United States on June 19, 2008
The Hollow Hope is written for the serious Court-watcher. It uses empirical data to deflate the notion that the Supreme Court influences significant social reform. However, it is written very clearly so even the novice who is serious about learning about judicial behavior and its impact on society can follow the arguments. Its first edition concentrated on Brown v. Board of Education (1954) and Roe v. Wade (1973)and related women's movement issues. It's second edition includes chapters on Goodridge v. Dept of Public Health (2003), wherein Massachusetts Supreme Court legalized same-sex marriage, and related equality cases involving same-sex couples. This updated work does not change the overall deflating thesis of the Hollow Hope. However, the second edition was published before the recent California Supreme Court decision legalizing same-sex marriage. A key counter-factual to the Hollow Hope is that public opinion in California favoring same-sex marriage changed after the Supreme Court ruling, not before. However, as with all empirical data, this correlation and time sequence does not prove that the Court actually moved public opinion; it may have reflected an opinion trend already underway. Moreover, since Californians still have an opportunity in Novemnber 2008 to reverse their Supreme Court with a state constitutional amendment, the thesis of the Hollow Hope may once again be proven true. Nonetheless, my bet is that the California context will emerge as the counter-factual to the thesis of the Hollow Hope.
7 people found this helpful
Report
Reviewed in the United States on August 9, 2014
Readable book. Provocative! I get the message, and I believe it....at times. The Court is usually behind public momentum and even public policy. But Rosenberg is an evangelical for this theory, to the detriment of complete rationality. I guess he has been attacked too often. This is a non-partisan book.
2 people found this helpful
Report
Reviewed in the United States on May 10, 2013
I did not want to accept his thesis, but really besides a few quibbles its rock solid. A very impressive work.
3 people found this helpful
Report